top of page

The Industrial Revolution Begins for AP World History

Jan 20

10 min read

0

10

0


The Industrial Revolution changed every part of the modern world. England was the first country to industrialize, but many other countries, including the United States, followed. Read the Google Slides to learn about how and why the Industrial Revolution began.




Causes of Industrialization

The emergence of industrialization first took root in regions with a confluence of favorable conditions. One of the earliest epicenters was England during the 18th century. England possessed several key characteristics that fueled industrialization. Access to rivers and canals, such as the Thames and the Manchester Ship Canal, facilitated the transportation of raw materials and finished goods, fostering efficient trade networks. The distribution of natural resources, particularly abundant coal fields in areas like Lancashire and Yorkshire, provided the energy required for the mechanization of industries, while iron and timber resources were also readily available.


The process of urbanization was pronounced in England as people migrated from rural areas to burgeoning industrial cities like Manchester and Birmingham, seeking employment in the expanding factories and mills. Improved agricultural productivity, driven by the Agricultural Revolution, released a surplus rural workforce, contributing to the labor pool for industrial enterprises. England’s colonial empire further enhanced its access to foreign resources, ensuring a steady supply of raw materials from overseas.


The accumulation of capital was a hallmark of England’s industrialization, with entrepreneurs reinvesting profits into technological advancements and the expansion of industries. These factors collectively positioned England as the pioneering hub of industrialization, with its textile, coal, and iron industries at the forefront. The success of the industrialization process in England set a precedent for other regions, including parts of Western Europe and the northeastern United States, where similar conditions and characteristics fostered the growth of industries and the transformation of economies.

Waterways

The importance of waterways in industrialization cannot be overstated, as they played a pivotal role in shaping the trajectory and success of burgeoning industries during the 18th and 19th centuries. Waterways, including rivers and canals, provided a reliable and cost-effective means of transportation for raw materials, finished goods, and resources essential for industrial processes. In regions with well-developed water transport systems, such as England’s extensive network of rivers and canals, the movement of goods became significantly more efficient, reducing transportation costs and facilitating the growth of industries.


Waterways also played a crucial role in the establishment of industrial centers. Proximity to navigable rivers and canals allowed industries to strategically locate themselves, ensuring a steady supply of raw materials and facilitating the distribution of finished products to markets. Factories and mills situated along water routes could easily transport goods to urban centers and ports for trade, contributing to the expansion of regional and international commerce.


Moreover, waterways powered industrial machinery during the early phases of industrialization. Waterwheels and later steam engines, often fueled by coal transported via water routes, provided the energy necessary for mechanized production processes. This utilization of water power was particularly significant in driving the early textile and manufacturing industries.


In essence, the accessibility and efficiency of water transportation systems were a cornerstone of industrialization. Regions with well-developed waterways experienced accelerated economic growth, as industries thrived on the ease of transportation, strategic location, and the energy harnessed from flowing water, contributing to the transformative period of industrial development.


Coal, Iron, and Timber

The geographical distribution of coal, iron, and timber played a pivotal role in the process of industrialization during the 18th and 19th centuries. These natural resources were essential inputs for key industries such as metallurgy, textile manufacturing, and construction, forming the bedrock of industrial development. Regions endowed with abundant coal deposits, such as the coalfields of England, provided a readily available and efficient source of energy for powering steam engines and fueling industrial processes. This accessibility to coal was a driving force behind the mechanization of industries, leading to increased productivity and economic growth.


Iron ore, another critical resource, was essential for the production of machinery, infrastructure, and transportation networks. Regions with substantial iron deposits, like the Ironbridge Gorge in England and the Ruhr Valley in Germany, became industrial powerhouses, supplying the raw materials necessary for the construction of railways, bridges, and the machinery that fueled the Industrial Revolution

Timber, with its versatility and use in construction and shipbuilding, also played a significant role in industrialization. Regions blessed with abundant forests, such as the northeastern United States and parts of Scandinavia, had a strategic advantage in supporting the construction of factories, housing for workers, and the ships that facilitated international trade.


The geographical distribution of these resources dictated the economic fortunes of regions during the era of industrialization. Areas with a fortuitous combination of coal, iron, and timber resources became industrial hubs, driving economic transformation, technological innovation, and urbanization. The strategic availability of these resources not only fueled industrial processes but also influenced the spatial distribution of industries, shaping the economic landscape and contributing to the rise of industrialized nations.


The Agricultural Revolution

The Agricultural Revolution, spanning the 18th and 19th centuries, marked a transformative period in human history characterized by significant advancements in farming practices and technology. Key innovations such as crop rotation, enclosure movements, and the selective breeding of livestock revolutionized traditional agricultural methods. Crop rotation, where different crops were planted in succession, enhanced soil fertility and increased yields. Enclosure movements involved consolidating and enclosing land, leading to more efficient land use and improved farming productivity. Additionally, selective breeding allowed for the development of high-yield and disease-resistant plant and animal varieties.


These innovations had profound effects on food production, leading to a substantial increase in agricultural output. The surplus food supply not only sustained a growing population but also freed up labor from farming activities. This surplus labor became available for other pursuits, contributing to the rise of industrialization as people migrated from rural areas to urban centers seeking employment in the emerging industrial sectors.


The Agricultural Revolution also facilitated the shift from subsistence agriculture to commercial farming. New machinery, such as the seed drill and the threshing machine, mechanized various aspects of farming, making it more efficient and less labor-intensive. These technological advancements not only increased productivity but also paved the way for the mechanization of agriculture in subsequent centuries.


In summary, the Agricultural Revolution was a watershed moment in human history, fundamentally altering the way food was produced and laying the groundwork for subsequent societal changes. The innovations in farming practices and technology unleashed a cascade of effects, from increased food production to the liberation of surplus labor, setting the stage for the industrial transformations that would follow.


Urbanization

During the 18th century, the Agricultural Revolution laid the groundwork by increasing agricultural productivity, resulting in a surplus rural population. This surplus labor, no longer required for traditional farming, migrated to expanding urban centers in search of new economic opportunities. The enclosure movements, which consolidated and privatized agricultural land, also contributed to rural-to-urban migration as displaced farmers sought employment in emerging industries.


Simultaneously, technological advancements in manufacturing and transportation set the stage for the Industrial Revolution. The development of machinery, such as the spinning jenny and the power loom, revolutionized textile production. As industries mechanized, urban areas became focal points for factory construction and manufacturing activities. The expansion of trade and commerce, facilitated by improved transportation infrastructure such as canals and later railways, further concentrated economic activities in urban centers.


The allure of urban life was also fueled by social and cultural factors. Cities offered diverse amenities, including educational institutions, cultural events, and social gatherings. The promise of a more varied and stimulating lifestyle, coupled with economic opportunities, attracted a growing population to urban areas. Additionally, the emergence of a capitalist economy and the pursuit of profit led to the establishment of factories in urban settings, transforming cities into bustling hubs of industry.


In summary, the prelude to the Industrial Revolution witnessed a significant influx of people into urban centers, driven by surplus agricultural labor, technological advancements, and economic opportunities. This mass migration laid the foundation for the concentrated industrialization that characterized the transformative period of the Industrial Revolution in the late 18th and early 19th centuries.


The Legal Protection of Private Property

The legal protection of private property leading up to the Industrial Revolution played a crucial role in shaping the economic landscape and paving the way for the transformative changes of the era. In the centuries preceding the Industrial Revolution, legal frameworks evolved to recognize and safeguard individual property rights. This marked a departure from earlier communal or feudal systems, where land and resources were often held collectively or controlled by aristocratic elites. The establishment of legal protections for private property allowed individuals to own, inherit, and trade land and assets with security and legal certainty.


The legal protection of private property incentivized agricultural improvements during the Agricultural Revolution. Farmers, confident in their property rights, were motivated to invest in new farming techniques and technologies. Enclosure movements, facilitated by legal recognition of property rights, led to the consolidation and privatization of land, enabling more efficient and productive agricultural practices.


Moreover, the legal protection of private property was a cornerstone of the emerging capitalist economy. It provided a foundation for the accumulation of capital, as individuals could invest in ventures beyond agriculture. Entrepreneurs and investors, assured of the security of their property, were more inclined to risk capital in industrial endeavors, such as the establishment of factories and the development of innovative machinery.


The legal protection of private property, therefore, created a stable and conducive environment for the economic shifts that characterized the Industrial Revolution. It empowered individuals to engage in entrepreneurial activities, invest in industrial enterprises, and contribute to the profound economic and social changes that unfolded during this transformative period in history.


Access to Foreign Resources

Access to foreign resources played a pivotal role in influencing industrialization during the 18th and 19th centuries. Industrializing nations sought to secure reliable access to raw materials, such as cotton, minerals, and metals, as well as new markets for their manufactured goods. The expansion of overseas trade and colonial ventures allowed industrializing powers to tap into the resources of their colonies or trading partners. For example, Britain’s industrialization was significantly fueled by access to cotton from its colonies, particularly India and the American South, which powered the textile industry. Similarly, access to iron ore and coal from overseas sources, combined with advancements in transportation like steamships, facilitated the growth of the iron and steel industry.


Furthermore, foreign resources contributed to the development of industries by providing a diverse range of materials and inputs. Rubber, tea, spices, and other commodities from colonies became integral to various manufacturing processes. The globalization of trade routes allowed industrializing nations to leverage the comparative advantages of different regions, promoting specialization and efficiency.


However, this access to foreign resources also gave rise to complex economic relationships, including imperialistic endeavors and exploitative practices. Industrializing powers often sought to secure control over resource-rich territories, leading to colonial expansions and geopolitical tensions.


In essence, access to foreign resources played a dual role in shaping industrialization – it provided the necessary inputs for industrial growth and fueled economic dependencies and global power dynamics. The quest for foreign resources became a driving force behind the industrialization process, contributing to the interconnectedness of economies on a global scale.


The Accumulation of Capital

The accumulation of capital played a pivotal role in driving the process of industrialization during the 18th and 19th centuries. Capital accumulation refers to the systematic growth of wealth through savings, investments, and the reinvestment of profits into productive enterprises. In the prelude to industrialization, various factors contributed to the accumulation of capital. The rise of merchant capitalism, spurred by expanding trade networks and colonial ventures, generated substantial profits. Merchants and traders accumulated wealth through commerce, creating a pool of capital that could be redirected toward industrial ventures.


The Agricultural Revolution also played a crucial role in capital accumulation. Increased agricultural productivity resulted in surplus food production, releasing a portion of the population from farming activities. This surplus labor force, in turn, sought employment in emerging industries. The profits generated by these industries were reinvested, contributing to the growing pool of capital.


As economies transitioned from agrarian to industrial, the accumulation of capital became a driving force behind technological innovations and the establishment of factories. Entrepreneurs and investors, fueled by the desire for profit, directed their accumulated capital into mechanized production processes. The invention of new machinery, such as the spinning jenny and power loom, transformed industries like textiles, enhancing productivity and profitability.


Moreover, the establishment of banking and financial institutions facilitated the mobilization of capital. Access to credit and investment opportunities allowed entrepreneurs to leverage accumulated capital for industrial expansion. The formation of joint-stock companies and stock exchanges provided avenues for individuals to invest in industrial enterprises, further fostering the growth of industries.


The Domestic System

The domestic system, also known as the putting-out system, was a method of production that emerged in the 18th century, predating the factory system of the Industrial Revolution. In this system, work was decentralized, and various stages of production were carried out in individual homes or small workshops. The domestic system was particularly prominent in the textile industry.


In the context of textile production, the domestic system involved tasks such as spinning and weaving being performed by individual households or small groups of workers. Merchants or entrepreneurs provided raw materials to these workers and then collected the finished goods for sale. This system allowed for a degree of flexibility in working hours and enabled rural populations to engage in manufacturing without having to relocate to urban centers.


The domestic system played a crucial role in the early phases of industrialization, especially in textile production, before the widespread adoption of factory-based manufacturing. As technological advancements and the demand for increased production efficiency grew, the domestic system eventually gave way to the factory system, where manufacturing processes were centralized in large-scale industrial facilities.


The Factory System

The factory system was a key component of the Industrial Revolution and marked a significant shift in the organization of production. It emerged in the late 18th and early 19th centuries, fundamentally transforming the way goods were manufactured. The factory system replaced traditional methods of production, which were often decentralized and carried out in small workshops or homes.


In the factory system, production was centralized within large industrial establishments known as factories. These factories housed machinery and employed a large number of workers, creating a more efficient and streamlined production process. The use of machinery, powered initially by water wheels and later by steam engines, allowed for increased output and productivity compared to manual labor.

Key features of the factory system included the concentration of workers in a single location, the division of labor, and the supervision of production by factory owners or managers. Workers, instead of working in dispersed locations, were brought together under one roof, allowing for better control and coordination of the manufacturing process. The division of labor involved breaking down the production process into specialized tasks, with each worker responsible for a specific aspect of production. This division of labor increased efficiency but often led to repetitive and monotonous work for individual workers.


The factory system was particularly prominent in textile manufacturing, where innovations like the spinning jenny and power loom revolutionized the industry. Over time, the factory system expanded to other industries, including iron and steel production, leading to the rapid industrialization of many economies.


While the factory system brought about increased efficiency and higher production volumes, it also raised social and labor-related challenges. Workers often faced long hours, harsh working conditions, and inadequate wages. The rise of the factory system contributed to the emergence of labor movements advocating for workers’ rights and better working conditions. Despite its challenges, the factory system played a central role in shaping the modern industrialized world.




Would you prefer to watch a video about the Industrial Revolution?





Nationalism and Revolutions

Unit 5: Revolutions

AP World History



The Industrial Revolution Begins

#APWorldHistory #IndustrialRevolution

Jan 20

10 min read

0

10

0

Comments

Share Your ThoughtsBe the first to write a comment.
bottom of page